Skip to main content

Gambling to Optimize Expected Median Bankroll

Poisson Games and Sudden-Death Overtime

Let's say we have a game that can be reasonably modeled as two independent Poisson processes with team \(i\) having parameter \(\lambda_i\). If one team wins in regulation with team \(i\) scoring \(n_i\), then it's well-known we have the MLE estimate \(\hat{\lambda_i}=n_i\). But what if the game ends in a tie in regulation with each team scoring \(n\) goals and we have sudden-death overtime? How does this affect the MLE estimate for the winning and losing teams?

Assuming without loss of generality that team \(1\) is the winner in sudden-death overtime. As we have two independent Poisson processes, the probability of this occurring is \(\frac{\lambda_1}{\lambda_1 + \lambda_2}\). Thus, the overall likelihood we'd like to maximize is \[L = e^{-\lambda_1} \frac{{\lambda_1}^n}{n!} e^{-\lambda_2} \frac{{\lambda_2}^n}{n!} \frac{\lambda_1}{\lambda_1 + \lambda_2}.\] Letting \(l = \log{L}\) we get \[l = -{\lambda_1} + n \log{\lambda_1} - {\lambda_2} + n \log{\lambda_2} - 2 \log{n!} + \log{\lambda_1}-\log({\lambda_1 + \lambda_2}).\] This gives \[\begin{equation}
\eqalign{
\frac{\partial l}{\partial \lambda_1} &= -1+\frac{n}{\lambda_1}+\frac{1}{\lambda_1}+\frac{1}{\lambda_1 + \lambda_2}\\
\frac{\partial l}{\partial \lambda_2} &= -1+\frac{n}{\lambda_2}+\frac{1}{\lambda_1 + \lambda_2}.
}
\end{equation}\] Setting both partials equal to \(0\) and solving, we get \[\begin{equation}
\eqalign{
(n-\hat{\lambda_1})(\hat{\lambda_1}+\hat{\lambda_2})+\hat{\lambda_2} &= 0\\
(n-\hat{\lambda_2})(\hat{\lambda_1}+\hat{\lambda_2})-\hat{\lambda_2} &= 0,
}
\end{equation}\] and so \[\begin{equation}
\eqalign{
\hat{\lambda_1} &= (n+1) \frac{2n}{2n+1}\\
\hat{\lambda_2} &= n \frac{2n}{2n+1}.
}
\end{equation}\] For example, if both teams score \(3\) goals in regulation and team \(1\) wins in sudden-death overtime, our MLE estimates are \(\hat{\lambda_1} = 3\frac{3}{7}, \hat{\lambda_2} = 2\frac{4}{7}\).

Intuitively this makes sense, because \(2n\) goals were scored in regulation time, hence we "expect" that the overtime goal occurred around a fraction \(\frac{1}{2n}\) of regulation, so team \(1\) scored \(n+1\) goals in about \(\frac{2n+1}{2n}\) regulation periods and team \(2\) scored \(n\) goals in about \(\frac{2n+1}{2n}\) regulation periods. The standard Poisson process MLE estimates here coincide with the estimates we derived above.

Does this work in practice? Yes! I tested it on my NCAA men's lacrosse model, and it increased the out-of-sample testing accuracy by 0.5%. Surprisingly large for such a small change!

Comments

Popular posts from this blog

A Bayes' Solution to Monty Hall

For any problem involving conditional probabilities one of your greatest allies is Bayes' Theorem. Bayes' Theorem says that for two events A and B, the probability of A given B is related to the probability of B given A in a specific way.

Standard notation:

probability of A given B is written \( \Pr(A \mid B) \)
probability of B is written \( \Pr(B) \)

Bayes' Theorem:

Using the notation above, Bayes' Theorem can be written: \[ \Pr(A \mid B) = \frac{\Pr(B \mid A)\times \Pr(A)}{\Pr(B)} \]Let's apply Bayes' Theorem to the Monty Hall problem. If you recall, we're told that behind three doors there are two goats and one car, all randomly placed. We initially choose a door, and then Monty, who knows what's behind the doors, always shows us a goat behind one of the remaining doors. He can always do this as there are two goats; if we chose the car initially, Monty picks one of the two doors with a goat behind it at random.

Assume we pick Door 1 and then Monty sho…

Mixed Models in R - Bigger, Faster, Stronger

When you start doing more advanced sports analytics you'll eventually starting working with what are known as hierarchical, nested or mixed effects models. These are models that contain both fixed and random effects. There are multiple ways of defining fixed vs random random effects, but one way I find particularly useful is that random effects are being "predicted" rather than "estimated", and this in turn involves some "shrinkage" towards the mean.

Here's some R code for NCAA ice hockey power rankings using a nested Poisson model (which can be found in my hockey GitHub repository):
model <- gs ~ year+field+d_div+o_div+game_length+(1|offense)+(1|defense)+(1|game_id) fit <- glmer(model, data=g, verbose=TRUE, family=poisson(link=log) ) The fixed effects are year, field (home/away/neutral), d_div (NCAA division of the defense), o_div (NCAA division of the offense) and game_length (number of overtime periods); off…

Gambling to Optimize Expected Median Bankroll

Gambling to optimize your expected bankroll mean is extremely risky, as you wager your entire bankroll for any favorable gamble, making ruin almost inevitable. But what if, instead, we gambled not to maximize the expected bankroll mean, but the expected bankroll median?

Let the probability of winning a favorable bet be \(p\), and the net odds be \(b\). That is, if we wager \(1\) unit and win, we get back \(b\) units (in addition to our wager). Assume our betting strategy is to wager some fraction \(f\) of our bankroll, hence \(0 \leq f \leq 1\). By our assumption, our betting strategy is invariant with respect to the actual size of our bankroll, and so if we were to repeat this gamble \(n\) times with the same \(p\) and \(b\), the strategy wouldn't change. It follows we may assume an initial bankroll of size \(1\).

Let \( q = 1-p \). Now, after \(n\)  such gambles our bankroll would have a binomial distribution with probability mass function \[ \Pr(k,n,p) = \binom{n}{k} p^k q^{n-k…